Rising Import Tariffs, Falling Export Growth: When Modern Supply Chains Meet Old-Style Protectionism

We examine the impacts of the 2018-2019 U.S. import tariff increases on U.S. export growth through the lens of supply chain linkages. Using 2016 confidential firm-trade linked data, we identify firms that eventually faced tariff increases. They accounted for 84% of all exports and represented 65% of manufacturing employment. For the average affected firm, the implied cost is $900 per worker in new duties. We construct product-level measures of exporters' exposure to import tariff increases and estimate the impact on U.S. export growth. The most exposed products had relatively lower export growth in 2018-2019, with larger effects in 2019. The decline in export growth in 2019Q3, for example, is equivalent to an ad valorem tariff on U.S. exports of 2% for the typical product and up to 4% for products with higher than average exposure.

The Census Bureau's Disclosure Review Board and Disclosure Avoidance Officers have reviewed this data product for unauthorized disclosure of confidential information and have approved the disclosure avoidance practices applied to this release (DRB Approval Numbers: CBDRB- FY19-519, CBDRB-FY20-104, CBDRB-FY20-CES006-004, CBDRB-FY20-CES006-005). We thank Chad Bown, Teresa Fort, Colin Hottman, Soumaya Keynes, CJ Krizan, Frank Li, and seminar and conference participants at the Federal Reserve Board, University of Michigan, Mid-Atlantic International Trade Workshop, U.S. Census Bureau, Stanford University, University of Virginia, Georgetown University, George Washington University, IDB, Rowan University, and FREIT ETOS for helpful comments and discussions. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Census Bureau, other members of the research staff at the Board of Governors, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or the National Bureau of Economic Research.

MARC RIS BibTeΧ

Download Citation Data

  • January 2, 2020

Mentioned in the News

More from nber.

In addition to working papers , the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter , the NBER Digest , the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , the Bulletin on Health , and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship  — as well as online conference reports , video lectures , and interviews .

2024, 16th Annual Feldstein Lecture, Cecilia E. Rouse," Lessons for Economists from the Pandemic" cover slide

  • Feldstein Lecture
  • Presenter: Cecilia E. Rouse

 2024 Methods Lecture, Susan Athey, "Analysis and Design of Multi-Armed Bandit Experiments and Policy Learning"

  • Methods Lectures
  • Presenter: Susan Athey

2024, Economics of Social Security Panel, "Earnings Inequality and Payroll Tax Revenues"

  • Panel Discussion
  • Presenters: Karen Dynan , Karen Glenn, Stephen Goss, Fatih Guvenen & James Pearce

BRIEF RESEARCH REPORT article

Research on the impact of covid-19 on import and export strategies.

Wenguang Tang

  • 1 College of Science, Tianjin University of Commerce, Tianjin, China
  • 2 Laboratory of Basic Psychology, Behavioral Analysis and Programmatic Development PAD-LAB, Catholic University of Cuenca, Cuenca, Ecuador
  • 3 Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, Princess Nourah Bint Abdulrahman University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia

Due to the spread of COVID-19, the public health crisis is bound to have a huge impact on the world economy and international trade. How to study the import and export strategies under the coronavirus pandemic has become a major issue that many scholars need to solve urgently. Therefore, a two-stage game model is constructed, and the reverse solution method is used to obtain the optimal output of enterprises in importing countries and exporting countries before and after the outbreak of pandemic, as well as the optimal subsidies for enterprises from exporting countries and the optimal import quarantine rate for importing countries. Based on the game between the two countries without the pandemic outbreak, the impact of the pandemic on the output, profits, and social welfare of enterprises in the two countries was compared. Enterprises in exporting countries face double threats from the pandemic and import quarantine fees. The increase in import quarantine fees reduces the social welfare of exporting countries. In order to effectively control the spread of the pandemic, subsidies are an effective means to restore exports to normal. Reasonable collection of import quarantine fees by importing countries can promote bilateral trade, but an excessive collection will be counterproductive. The governments of exporting countries should establish emergency mechanisms and relevant subsidy policies, and enterprises should continuously improve their competitiveness. At the same time, countries should abandon the concept of trade protection and negotiate and cooperate to jointly deal with the pandemic.

Introduction

With the ongoing global pandemic of COVID-19, the unprecedented public health crisis is bound to have a huge negative impact on the world economy, environment and international economic and trade cooperation ( Razzaq et al., 2020 ; Khan et al., 2021 ; Yu et al., 2021 ; Irfan et al., 2022 ). The forecast report released by the World Trade Organization in 2020 pointed out that the pandemic will significantly shrink global trade. After the pandemic outbreak, the scale of global import and export trade showed a sharp decline amid fluctuations. In the first half of 2020, the year-on-year decline in global import and export trade scale reached 11.98% and 13.48%, respectively. The above-mentioned restrictive measures will lead to an obvious trade-inhibitory effect, the direct consequence of which is to weaken the degree of trade liberalization between countries, leading to high market access barriers, sharp rise in trade costs, and may even induce trade protectionism ( Shahzad et al., 2021 ). Therefore, under the impact of the Coronavirus pandemic, how to alleviate the adverse impact of the pandemic to promote international trade to enter the fast lane of recovery has become a major issue that the international community urgently needs to deal with.

Due to the rapid spread of COVID-19 worldwide, countries worldwide have to take trade protection measures ( Xuefeng et al., 2021 ), the international free trade system is increasingly fragile, and new trade barriers are gradually formed. Taking China as an example, in foreign trade, statistics from the General Administration of Customs show that most enterprises with actual import and export results in 2019 are private enterprises, with the number reaching 406,000. In addition, among the export-oriented enterprises in China, small, medium and micro enterprises contribute about 60% of the total national import and export ( Zhang, 2020 ). The addition of such an entry quarantine fee by foreign governments is a severe blow to many export-oriented enterprises facing difficulties in China at the moment. Therefore, export-oriented enterprises must not expand their production blindly because of a series of favorable policies introduced by the state. Each enterprise should reasonably adjust its output and set the optimal production decision according to the international market situation.

The COVID-19 is characterized by high risk, suddenness, and rapid spread and is a typical global public health emergency. It is well known that sudden major public health events usually affect the normal operation of political, economic, and social activities, some scholars conduct research on sudden public health events in the context of social emergency management ( Sun et al., 2014 ; Liang et al., 2019 ; Xi and Zang, 2020 ). Numerous scholars have argued that this COVID-19 has created potential trade barriers and negatively impacted exports. ( Duan et al., 2020 ). noted that more than 18 million SMEs in China were severely affected by the pandemic, most of which have export-led businesses. ( Baldwin and Di Mauro, 2020 ). argued that this COVID-19 pandemic will have a more severe impact on the economy and environment than any other pandemic since World War II, with border closures and factory shutdowns, which will cause a significant drop in exports of the corresponding industries in the countries where the pandemic occurred. Meanwhile, some scholars have proposed policy recommendations for the government to respond to major public health events such as the pandemic from the perspective of maintaining foreign trade. For example Wang and Zhang (2020) , point out that the pandemic may cause significant losses to export country’s economies and trade, and is a major test of national governance system and governance capacity. According to ( Shen, 2020 ), countries need to “stabilize foreign trade” and support import and employment growth by stabilizing the export market, and the government should help enterprises to resume work and production in an orderly manner and introduce policies such as tax reduction and fee reduction. However, these studies usually focus on studying the situation in a single country and fail to consider the interactions between the two countries in terms of import and export.

The related research on the analysis of oligopoly competition strategy is one of the commonly used methods to construct an application scenario model based on game theory, analyze the influence of different strategic behaviors and the changing trend of important variables by means of numerical simulation. Based on the US Rice Export Program to Japan and South Korea ( Lee and Kennedy, 2006 ), attempted to analyze both import markets incorporating econometric estimates and public choice theory in a game-theoretic framework. Du and Wang (2018) proposed a multi-level threshold public goods game model to research how income redistribution affects the evolution of global cooperation. The effect of different thresholds on the strategy was investigated by numerical simulation. Andoni et al. (2021) modeled the problem of deducing how much capacity each player should build as a non-cooperative Stackelberg-Cournot game. Using data-driven analysis to analyze investor decision-making. Based on the game theory ( Yang et al., 2021 ), analyzed the behavior of countries when carrying out regional cooperation to govern the epidemic and put forward specific cooperative income distribution schemes according to the different attributes of the countries. Using numerical simulations, they analyze the effect of the variation of different parameters on the utility of the two countries in different cooperation situations.

Scholars have also conducted many studies on the use of game theory to study bilateral trade. Ferreira and Ferreira (2009) considered an international trade under the Bertrand model with differentiated products and unknown production costs. The impact of tariff changes on corporate profits is analyzed. Yang and Wei (2013) constructed a three-stage game model for the continuation of the United States carbon tariff policy based on a two-stage game model in which the United States implemented a carbon tax policy only on its domestic enterprises and introduced a carbon tariff on imports from China. The impact of carbon tariffs on trade between China and the United States is analyzed. Xie et al. (2016) construct a theoretical game model in which a domestic firm exports to a third country through an intermediary in the third country and competes with a firm located in another country that exports directly to the third country. It is analyzed whether the bargaining power affects the choice of a country’s strategic trade policy when a country firm chooses a third-country intermediary to export its products. Xie et al. (2018) constructed a model of duopoly international market competition in which producers compete on price against the background of product quality differences and with the actual situation of Chinese exporters. And on this basis, using game theory, a country’s optimal strategic trade policy is explored in terms of trade benefits and social welfare. Mizuno and Takauchi (2020) considered a third-market model with a vertical trading structure. The change in optimal export policy as product-substitutability increases is examined, along with a discussion of welfare comparisons between the downstream Gounod and Bertrand cases.

In order to study the impact of the pandemic on import and export strategies and the changes in the profits and social welfare of companies in various countries under the pandemic, we used game theory to model the import and export strategies under the impact of the pandemic. Compared with the existing literature, the contributions of this paper are mainly reflected in the following aspects: under the pandemic, we examined the impact of the collection of import quarantine fees on the production strategies of importing and exporting countries; under the pandemic, we have given the optimal subsidy strategy of exporting countries based on their own social welfare; under the pandemic, we compared the changes in the enterprises’ profits and social welfare of the respective governments after the game between importing and exporting countries, and analyzed the measures that importers and exporters should take to deal with the impact of the pandemic jointly.

Theoretical Model

Problem description and assumptions.

Consider two countries: an exporter ( E country) and an importer ( I country). Similar to the setting in Xie et al. (2018) , Tang et al. (2020) , Mizuno and Takauchi (2020) , Tang et al. (2020) , we assume that each of them has only one enterprise (enterprise E and enterprise I , respectively) that produces a homogeneous product. The products produced by the exporting enterprise E are all exported to the importing I country, and the products of the importing enterprise I can only be sold in its own market, i.e., the importing country is the only consumer of the product. There are two sources of supply in the production market: in addition to the domestic enterprises, they can also import from the exporting E country. We further make the following assumptions. The marginal cost of production, transportation, and tariffs for the exporting country is c E , and the marginal cost of production for the importing country is c I . Since enterprises in the exporting country have relatively low costs, this paper assumes that 0 < c E < c I . Since consumers in the importing I country consume only one homogeneous product, the demand function for the product is:

where a > 0 is the potential price of the product, b > 0 is the sensitivity of price to output, Q E and Q I represent the output of enterprises in the exporting E country and importing I country, respectively.

When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, the government of the importing country, to protect its national health and the share of its own enterprises in the market, will enhance the exporting country enterprises to impose a unit of production import quarantine fee τ > 0 . At this point, the government of the exporting country, in order to maintain the normal operation of export enterprises, will choose to encourage exports in the short term by giving export enterprises relevant subsidy s > 0 . These assumptions are mostly common practices, thus can be made without the loss of generality of this study. The notations and variables used in our analysis are shown in Table 1 .

www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1 . Model notations and variables.

Game Model of Two Enterprises in the Absence of a Pandemic

When there is no pandemic, the enterprises of the two countries compete in Cournot game in the consuming country I (importing country). Enterprises’ profits π E ( Q E , Q I ) and π I ( Q E , Q I ) are given by (see Fernanda A.)

The enterprises of each country determine the optimal output by maximizing their profits, and the maximization problem can be expressed as:

From the first-order condition of the optimization problem ( Eq. 1 ) equation, we know that when a > 2 c I − c E , the optimal output of the enterprises in the two countries are:

This leads to the optimal price of the product and the optimal profit of the two enterprises, respectively:

Property 1. In the absence of a pandemic, the enterprise’s optimal output is a decreasing function of the marginal cost of products from domestic enterprise, is an increasing function of the marginal cost of products of the enterprise from other country; the product price is an increasing function of the marginal cost of the product of the enterprise from both countries.Since Q E ∗ − Q I ∗ = c I − c E b and π E ∗ − π I ∗ = ( 2 a − c E − c I ) ( c I − c E ) 9 b , and since c I > c E and a > 2 c I − c E , we obtain the following property.

Property 2. Enterprises in exporting country have higher output and profit than enterprises in importing countries due to their lower marginal costs, i.e.,

Game Model of Two Countries When a Pandemic Occurs in the Exporting Country

When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, on the one hand, the importing country will impose an additional import quarantine fee τ , and the exporting country will give enterprises subsidy s , the profit structure of exporting enterprises changes. On the other hand, the price of raw materials rises and additional protective equipment lead to an increase in the marginal cost of exporting enterprises, which is recorded as c E m , and c E m > c E . At this point, the game process between the two governments and enterprises is divided into two stages: in the first stage, due to the pandemic in the exporting country, the exporting government determines the optimal subsidy s ∗ to the exporting enterprise based on maximizing its social welfare after learning that the importing country imposes import quarantine fees τ on the exporting enterprise; in the second stage, after the enterprises observe the optimal subsidies given to the enterprises of the exporting country, the enterprises of the two countries conduct the Cournot game to determine their respective optimal output. For this two-stage Stackelberg game, we use the inverse solution method to find the optimal solutions of each stage with reference to Tang et al. (2020) , Tang et al. (2021) , and the superscript denotes the game with pandemic.

Consider the game process of the second stage. The enterprise’s profit is given by

at this time, the profit per unit product of the exporting country’s enterprise has changed. The enterprises in both countries maximize the profits to determine their optimal output Q E m ∗ ,   Q I m ∗ , the game model is:

where the demand function for the product is P m = a − b ( Q E m + Q I m ) ; τ is a constant, which indicates the import quarantine fees levied by the government of the importing country for enterprises in the exporting country.

From the first-order conditions of the optimization problem (2), the optimal price of the product and the optimal output of the two enterprises are obtained as:

Property 3. When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, the exporting country’s subsidies for its own enterprises will increase the export volume of its own enterprises, reduce the output of the importing enterprises, and lower the price of the product; the import quarantine fees imposed by the importing country on the exporting country will reduce the export of the exporting country, increase the output of its own enterprises, and increase the price of the product.Since Q E m ∗ ( s ) − Q E m ∗ ( s ) = − c E m + c I + s − τ b , the following property can be obtained.

Property 4. When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country

(1) If s < c E m − c I + τ , the output of enterprises in the exporting country is less than the output of enterprises in the importing country.

(2) If s > c E m − c I + τ , the output of the enterprises in the exporting country is greater than the output of the enterprises in the importing country.

It consists of the profits of enterprises minus subsidy expenses.Substituting the conclusion from Eq. 3 into Eq. 4 yields:

the optimal subsidy from the government of the exporting country to the enterprises should satisfy

From the fact that the second order derivative is less than 0 , there exists an unique optimal solution when a > 2 c E m − c I + 2 τ :

Due to the uncertainty of the pandemic, subsidy policy should be adjusted depending on the situation of the pandemic. Reasonable subsidies will also avoid trade protection by importing countries and promote healthy trade relations between the two countries. However, suppose high export subsidies are given to enterprises across the board for a long period of time. In that case, it will not only harm the interests of enterprises in the importing countries and cause unfair trade competition, but also inhibit technological innovation and weaken the intrinsic motivation of enterprises.

Property 5. When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, the optimal subsidy from the government of the exporting country to the enterprises is a decreasing function of the import quarantine fees in the importing country, a decreasing function of the marginal cost of the product of the enterprises in the exporting country, and an increasing function of the marginal production cost of the enterprises in the importing country.Substituting s ∗ into Eq. 3 yields the optimal output of the two enterprises in the case of a pandemic in the exporting country when − a + 3 c I 2 − c E m < τ < a + c I 2 − c E m , respectively:

Since the social welfare function of the importing country is:

it consists of the profit of domestic enterprises, consumer surplus and import inspection and quarantine fee income, where C S ( Q m ∗ ) indicates consumer surplus

The optimal price of the product, the profit of the two firms and the social welfare of the two countries can be obtained as:

Property 6. When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, the optimal output of enterprises in the exporting country, the profits of enterprises and the social welfare of the exporting country are all decreasing functions of import quarantine fees; the optimal output of enterprises in the importing country, the profits of enterprises and the prices of products are all increasing functions of import quarantine fees; when τ < 3 a − 2 c E m − c I 10 , the social welfare of the importing country is an increasing function of import quarantine fees, and when τ > 3 a − 2 c E m − c I 10 , the social welfare of the importing country is a decreasing function of import quarantine fees.

Comparison of Effects in Exporting Countries Without and With Pandemic

Using the absence of a pandemic as a benchmark, we compare the impact on product prices, production and profits of enterprises in both countries, and social welfare in both countries under the scenario of a pandemic in the exporting country.

Impact on Production, Product Prices and Corporate Profits of Enterprises in Both Countries

The optimal output of enterprises in both countries, the optimal price of the product and the social welfare of the governments in both countries are compared for the two scenarios, and the results are as follows:

Property 7.

(1) If c E m + τ < a + 4 c E m + c I 6 , the impact of the pandemic on exporters is small, and timely and effective subsidies from the exporting country’s government lead to an increase in production and profits for the exporting country’s enterprises, a decrease in optimal production and profits for the importing country’s enterprises, and a decrease in product prices.

(2) If a + c I 2 > c E m + τ > a + 4 c E m + c I 6 , the impact of the pandemic on exporters is greater at this time. The occurrence of the pandemic in the exporting country will lead to a reduction in production and profits of enterprises in the exporting country, an increase in production and profits of enterprises in the importing country, and a rise in product prices.

Impact on Social Welfare

To further analyze the impact of the COVID-19 on social welfare in both countries, numerical simulation is presented. Simulation explored the effect of import quarantine rates and the marginal cost of exporting enterprises on social welfare. For this quantitative demonstration, we assigned values to each parameter based on the assumptions described in the previous sections and the practical implications. The parameters a = 10 , b = 3 , c E = 1 , c I = 3.5 were used as the benchmark case when there is no pandemic. By calculating the optimal social welfare ( ω E m ∗ ) of exporting countries with different c E m and τ , we draw Figure 1 as follows, which describes the trend of social welfare of exporting countries with the import quarantine fee and different production cost.

www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1 . Trend of social welfare changes in exporting country. (Source: Simulation data for numerical calculations).

The upper horizontal line in Figure 1 is the social welfare of the exporting country in the absence of the pandemic, which is independent of τ and c E m . The lower three curves show the decreasing trend of social welfare in the exporting country for c E m = 2,3,4 , respectively. In addition, the increase of import quarantine fees brings a double blow to exporters; social welfare will be further reduced and decreases as τ increases. With c E m = 2 , for example, the social welfare of exporting countries decreases with the increase of import quarantine rate, and the levy of quarantine fees has a great impact on exporting countries. It is clear from the figure that when the quarantine rate is low, i.e., τ < τ 1 , exporters will still export, but when the quarantine rate exceeds τ 1 , exporters will not be able to afford the excessive tax and stop exporting, and trade is terminated.

In the face of the impact of the pandemic and the import quarantine fees imposed by importing countries, the government should strive to improve the competitiveness of its enterprises. Exporters should accelerate the pace of transformation and upgrading, reduce the marginal cost of production, continuously improve logistics efficiency, review the situation to improve their own management capacity and risk resistance and enhance the position of their products in the industrial chain and the competitiveness of the international market.

The trends of social welfare ( ω E m ∗ ) in importing countries with τ and c E m are shown in Figure 2 .

www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2 . Trends of social welfare changes in importing countries. (Source: Simulation data for numerical calculations).

The horizontal line in Figure 2 is the social welfare of the importing country in the absence of the pandemic, which is independent of τ and c E m . The three curves show the change of social welfare of importing countries with τ when c E m = 2,3,4 , respectively, and the curves show an increasing and then decreasing trend. Taking c E m = 3 as an example, it can be clearly seen that: 1) When τ < τ 2 The social welfare of the importing country is an increasing function of the import quarantine fee, and increasing the import quarantine fee will increase the social welfare. When τ 2 < τ < τ 4 , the social welfare of the importing country is a decreasing function of the import quarantine fee, and increasing the import quarantine fee at this time will make the social welfare decrease, indicating that the high quarantine fee does not improve the social welfare of the importing country; 2) And when τ < τ 1 or τ 3 < τ < τ 4 , the social welfare is lower than that of in the absence of pandemic, indicating that when the quarantine fee is too low or too high, the social welfare of the importing country due to the pandemic will lower; and when τ 1 < τ < τ 3 , the social welfare of the importing country is higher than before the pandemic, indicating that an appropriate import quarantine fee will increase the social welfare of the importing country; 3) When τ > τ 4 , the exporting country will not export the product due to the high import quarantine fee and the trade between the importing and exporting countries will stop.

To avoid trade frictions between bilateral countries and to avoid the increase of product prices in the domestic market and the reduction of consumer surplus, the importing country should only reasonably levy import quarantine fees to improve the market competitiveness of domestic enterprises, thereby increasing corporate profits and social welfare. However, the import quarantine fee levied by the importing country cannot be too high, otherwise, it will not only seriously damage the social welfare of the exporting country but also reduce the social welfare of the importing country itself, which is not conducive to the upgrading and transformation of domestic enterprises and the adjustment of industrial structure.

The trend in total social welfare ( ω E m ∗ + ω I m ∗ ) for both countries with τ and c E m is shown in Figure 3 .

www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3 . Trend of total social welfare in two countries. (Source: Simulation data for numerical calculations).

The horizontal line in Figure 3 is the sum of social welfare in the absence of the pandemic, which is independent of τ and c E m . The three curves show the change of the total of social welfare of the two countries with τ when c E m = 2,3,4 , and the curves show a decreasing trend. Affected by the pandemic, the social welfare of both countries are greatly reduced, and the greater the c E m , the more social welfare reduced; It can be seen from this that on the one hand, exporting countries should actively take measures to restore production capacity as soon as possible and reduce the cost of enterprises in the face of the pandemic; Social welfare has had a negative impact on the normal trade and economy of the two countries. The importing country should abandon trade protection and proceed from the overall situation of the trade between the two countries to jointly deal with the pandemic and achieve a win-win situation.

The government should be fully aware of the long-term nature and complexity of the game between the two countries and should respond to the WTO-compliant import quarantine fees imposed by the importing countries with a normal heart, and establish an early warning and response mechanism promptly, with the relevant subsidy policies for exporters. Both the governments and enterprises must actively negotiate with relevant governments and enterprises from both domestic and international perspectives and take the initiative to bear the impact of the pandemic on domestic and foreign trade.

In the face of the pandemic, exporting countries must first control the spread of the pandemic to reduce the costs of their enterprises. The tax exemption method or lowering export tax rate is a desirable fiscal policy to prevent enterprises from breaking their capital chains and help them smoothly overcome the hard times. Controlling the spread of the pandemic and subsidizing enterprises are effective means for exporting countries to restore the economy. However, it should not be overlooked that exporting countries make every effort to subsidize export enterprises, which will lead to unfair trade competition in the markets of importing countries, i.e., low-price competition of products, which reduces the profits of enterprises in exporting countries and reduces the profits of enterprises in importing countries, which is not conducive to the sustainable development of economy and trade.

The reasonable increase in import quarantine fees imposed by importing countries is conducive to enhancing the market competitiveness of their enterprises. However, when the importing country imposes higher import inspection and quarantine fees, not only seriously undermines the social welfare of the exporting country, bringing the possibility of trade friction between the two countries and promoting the increase in the price of products on the domestic market. Consumer surplus is reduced, which counterproductively reduces the country’s social welfare and is not conducive to the upgrading and industrial restructuring of domestic enterprises themselves. Therefore, the importing country should impose lower import quarantine fees to promote their social welfare and corporate profits. Importing countries should take other positive trade measures and exporting countries should cooperate fully to achieve a win-win situation.

When the pandemic comes, all countries should abandon trade protection, eliminate trade barriers, unblock trade channels, reasonably build stable supply chains and industrial chains, and commit to developing an equal, balanced, mutually beneficial and win-win trade partnership. Both exporting and importing countries must establish subsidies and import quarantine taxes that align with their own national conditions. On the one hand, they can promote healthy competition in the consumer market, and on the other hand, they must jointly respond to the negative impact of the pandemic on the economies of both countries. The two countries should actively conduct in-depth diplomatic consultations on the impact of the pandemic, promote the signing of bilateral border health and quarantine cooperation documents, and avoid the deterioration of trade relations and escalation of trade frictions caused by the pandemic. All countries should focus on long-term trade cooperation, adhere to the deeply intertwined model of mutually beneficial cooperation, clearly express their attitude and position to work together to overcome the pandemic, and resolutely oppose unilateral trade protection.

The research further enriches bilateral trade strategies’ theoretical connotation and practice under the pandemic. We only consider the situation of international duopoly competition. Still, the motive involving government intervention in the import and export of enterprises has always existed in the situation of multi-oligopoly competition. In particular, when the number of enterprises participating in international competition is more than one, the exporting country needs to consider the actual situation and negotiating power of each enterprise in formulating subsidy policies and balancing the competition effect among various enterprises. In addition, we only studied the pandemic situation in the exporting country and did not consider the pandemic situation in the importing country, nor did we consider the information asymmetry between enterprises and enterprises and between enterprises and governments. As future research, our model can be extended to multi-oligopoly competition while considering the asymmetry between firms and governments, making the model more realistic and challenging. Finally, the model is based on static decision-making, and we can also extend it to a dynamic decision-making model, that is, to study and analyze the evolution of import and export strategies over time. These deficiencies are left for future research to address.

Data Availability Statement

The raw data supporting the conclusion of this article will be made available by the authors, without undue reservation.

Author Contributions

WT issued the idea and design for the research. JH and JL analyzed the model and drafted the manuscript. GR and FM revised the manuscript along with other authors.

This research was supported by Tianjin Research Innovation Project for Postgraduate Students (2021YJSS278). Princess Nourah Bint Abdulrahman University Researchers Supporting Project number (PNURSP2022R260), Princess Nourah Bint Abdulrahman University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Andoni, M., Robu, V., Couraud, B., Fruh, W.-G., Norbu, S., and Flynn, D. (2021). Analysis of Strategic Renewable Energy, Grid and Storage Capacity Investments via Stackelberg-Cournot Modelling. IEEE Access 9, 37752–37771. doi:10.1109/ACCESS.2021.3062981

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Baldwin, R., and Di Mauro, B. W. (2020). Economics in the Time of COVID-19 . London: Centre for Economic Policy Research Press .

Google Scholar

Du, J., and Wang, B. (2018). Evolution of Global Cooperation in Multi-Level Threshold Public Goods Games with Income Redistribution. Front. Phys. 6, 67. doi:10.3389/fphy.2018.00067

Duan, H., Wang, S., and Yang, C. (2020). Coronavirus: Limit Short-Term Economic Damage. Nature 578 (7796), 578515–515. doi:10.1038/d41586-020-00522-6

Ferreira, F. A., and Ferreira, F. (2009). Maximum-revenue Tariff under Bertrand Duopoly with Unknown Costs. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simulation 14 (9-10), 3498–3502. doi:10.1016/j.cnsns.2009.01.026

Irfan, M., Razzaq, A., Suksatan, W., Sharif, A., Madurai Elavarasan, R., Yang, C., Hao, Y., and Rauf, A. (2022). Asymmetric Impact of Temperature on COVID-19 Spread in India: Evidence from Quantile-On-Quantile Regression Approach. J. Therm. Biol. 104, 103101. doi:10.1016/j.jtherbio.2021.103101

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Khan, S. A. R., Razzaq, A., Yu, Z., Shah, A., Sharif, A., and Janjua, L. (2021). Disruption in Food Supply Chain and Undernourishment Challenges: An Empirical Study in the Context of Asian Countries. Socio-Economic Plann. Sci. , 101033. doi:10.1016/j.seps.2021.101033

Lee, D.-S., and Kennedy, P. L. (2006). A Political Economic Analysis of U.S. Rice Export Programs to Japan and South Korea: A Game‐Theoretic Approach. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 88 (2), 420–431. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8276.2006.00868.x

Liang, W., Wu, D., and Guo, M. (2019). Discussion on the Establishment and Improvement of the Emergency Plan System for Nursing Emergencies in Public Health Events. Chin. J. Control. Endemic Dis. 34 (5), 548–549.

Mizuno, T., and Takauchi, K. (2020). Optimal export Policy with Upstream price Competition. Manchester Sch. 88 (2), 324–348. doi:10.1111/manc.12278

Razzaq, A., Sharif, A., Aziz, N., Irfan, M., and Jermsittiparsert, K. (2020). Asymmetric Link between Environmental Pollution and COVID-19 in the Top Ten Affected States of US: A Novel Estimations from Quantile-On-Quantile Approach. Environ. Res. 191, 110189. doi:10.1016/j.envres.2020.110189

Shahzad, F., Yannan, D., Kamran, H. W., Suksatan, W., Nik Hashim, N. A. A., and Razzaq, A. (2021). Outbreak of Epidemic Diseases and Stock Returns: an Event Study of Emerging Economy. Econ. Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja , 1–20. doi:10.1080/1331677x.2021.1941179

Shen, G. B. (2020). Impacts of the COVID-19 Pandemic on China’s Trade and Employment and Related Countermeasures. J. Shanghai Univ. Int. Business Econ. 27 (2), 16–25. doi:10.16060/j.cnki.issn2095-8072.2020.02.002

Sun, M., Wu, D., and Shi, J. F. (2014). Policies Change Related to Public Health Emergency Disposal in China: From 2003 to 2013. Chin. J. Health Pol. 7 (7), 24–29. doi:10.3969/j.issn.1674-2982.2014.07.004

Tang, W., Li, H., and Cai, K. (2020). Optimising the Credit Term Decisions in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 59 (14), 4324–4341. doi:10.1080/00207543.2020.1762018

Tang, W., Li, H., and Chen, J. (2021). Optimizing Carbon Taxation Target and Level: Enterprises, Consumers, or Both? J. Clean. Prod. 282, 124515. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124515

Wang, T. S., and Zhang, Q. (2020). Impact of COVID-19 on China’s Foreign Trade Enterprises and Countermeasures. Econ. Rev. J. 3, 23–29. doi:10.16528/j.cnki.22-1054/f.202003023

Xi, H., and Zang, L. Q. (2020). Research on Fundamental Problems and Key Nodes of Emergency Management of Public Health Emergencies. Acad. Res. 4, 1–7+177. doi:10.1155/2022/7513461

Xie, S. X., Liu, P. D., and Wang, X. S. (2018). Price Competition, Strategic Trade Policy Adjustment and Firms’ Export Mode Choicing. Econ. Res. J. 10, 127–141.

Xie, S. X., Shi, H. M., and Zang, M. X. (2016). The Bargaining Power and Strategic Trade Policies. The J. World Economy 7, 3–23. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0023478

Xuefeng, Z., Razzaq, A., Gokmenoglu, K. K., and Rehman, F. U. (2021). Time Varying Interdependency between COVID-19, Tourism Market, Oil Prices, and Sustainable Climate in United States: Evidence from advance Wavelet Coherence Approach. Econ. Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja , 1–23. doi:10.1080/1331677x.2021.1992642

Yang, H., Wu, Y., Yao, Y., Zhang, S., Zhang, S., Xie, L., et al. (2021). How to Reach a Regional Cooperation Mechanism to Deal with the Epidemic: An Analysis from the Game Theory Perspective. Front. Public Health 9, 738184. doi:10.3389/fpubh.2021.738184

Yang, S. H., and Wei, S. D. (2013). A Game Analysis on the Effects of Carbon Tariff on China and the United States. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. S2, 634–640. doi:10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2013.s2.021

Yu, Z., Razzaq, A., Rehman, A., Shah, A., Jameel, K., and Mor, R. S. (2021). Disruption in Global Supply Chain and Socio-Economic Shocks: a Lesson from COVID-19 for Sustainable Production and Consumption. Operations Manag. Res. , 1–16. doi:10.1007/s12063-021-00179-y

Zhang, X. H. (2020). The Impact of Novel Coronavirus Outbreak on Small and Micro Enterprises in China and Countermeasures. China Business And Market 34 (3), 26–34. doi:10.14089/j.cnki.cn11-3664/f.2020.03.004

Keywords: COVID-19, stackelberg game, import and export, import quarantine fee, strategies

Citation: Tang W, Hu J, Reivan Ortiz GG, Mabrouk F and Li J (2022) Research on the Impact of COVID-19 on Import and Export Strategies. Front. Environ. Sci. 10:891780. doi: 10.3389/fenvs.2022.891780

Received: 08 March 2022; Accepted: 30 March 2022; Published: 26 April 2022.

Reviewed by:

Copyright © 2022 Tang, Hu, Reivan Ortiz, Mabrouk and Li. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Wenguang Tang, [email protected]

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

Advertisement

Advertisement

Trade and growth in developing countries: the role of export composition, import composition and export diversification

  • Published: 03 August 2020
  • Volume 54 , pages 919–941, ( 2021 )

Cite this article

research paper on import and export

  • Carlos A. Carrasco   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-5439-4960 1 &
  • Edgar Demetrio Tovar-García 2  

2942 Accesses

42 Citations

3 Altmetric

Explore all metrics

We investigate the trade-economic growth nexus in developing countries considering the structure of the external sector. The economic literature has examined the effects on growth of export composition, export diversification and import composition, individually. We add to this discussion by jointly evaluating the role of these three factors in the trade-economic growth nexus. The assessment of the structure of the external sector allows identifying the features that improve the trade-economic growth nexus with relevant economic policy implications for developing countries. Using a sample of 19 developing countries and dynamic panel data models, we found that export composition and export diversification are insignificant. By contrast, the domestic content of exports, the share of high-tech imports and capital goods imports are positively associated with economic growth. Consequently, developing countries growth benefits from high-tech and capital goods imports, and potentially, from the development of an industrial policy able to boost the domestic production of inputs for the exporting sector.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save.

  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime

Price includes VAT (Russian Federation)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Rent this article via DeepDyve

Institutional subscriptions

research paper on import and export

Source : World Development Indicators, World Bank and Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD-Stats), IMF Statistics

Similar content being viewed by others

research paper on import and export

Import Substitution and Export-Led Growth

research paper on import and export

Export growth drivers and economic development

research paper on import and export

Export specialization, trade liberalization and economic growth: a synthetic control analysis

Although the positive role of high-tech intensity goods trade in export performance, productivity and economic growth is recognized in several empirical works, it is a matter of study the definition and measurement of high-tech goods and industries. While this is an interesting subject, it falls outside the scope of this paper. In this paper, we follow the updated OECD classification based on the proposal by Hatzichronoglou ( 1997 ). For a discussion on this regard, see Hatzichronoglou ( 1997 ), Carroll et al. ( 2000 ), Peneder ( 2003 ) and Srholec ( 2007 ).

We include the share of 14 export industries according to OECD classification to compute the Herfindahl–Hirschman index: agriculture, forestry and fishing; mining and quarrying; food products, beverages and tobacco; textiles, wearing apparel, leather and related products; paper and printing; chemicals, rubber, plastics and fuel products; other nonmetallic mineral products; basic metals and fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment; machinery and equipment; transport equipment; furniture, other manufacturing; electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply; other activities; total waste.

Abdi H, Williams LJ (2010) Principal component analysis. Wiley Interdiscip Rev Comput Stat 2:433–459. https://doi.org/10.1002/wics.101

Article   Google Scholar  

Aditya A, Acharyya R (2013) Export diversification, composition, and economic growth: evidence from cross-country analysis. J Int Trade Econ Dev 22:959–992. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2011.619009

Agosin MR (2008) Export diversification and growth in emerging economies. CEPAL Rev 97:115–131

Google Scholar  

Agosin MR, Alvarez R, Bravo-Ortega C (2012) Determinants of export diversification around the world: 1962–2000. World Econ 35:295–315. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2011.01395.x

Al-Marhubi F (2000) Export diversification and growth: an empirical investigation. Appl Econ Lett 7:559–562. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504850050059005

Amir-ud-Din R, Usman M, Abbas F, Javed SA (2019) Human versus physical capital: issues of accumulation, interaction and endogeneity. Econ Chang Restruct 52:351–382. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9225-2

Amurgo-Pacheco A, Pierola MD (2008) Patterns of export diversification in developing countries: intensive and extensive margins

Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

Awokuse TO (2008) Trade openness and economic growth: is growth export-led or import-led? Appl Econ 40:161–173. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840600749490

Banga K (2016) Impact of global value chains on employment in India. J Econ Integr 31:631–673. https://doi.org/10.11130/jei.2016.31.3.631

Barro RJ (1999) Notes on growth accounting. J Econ Growth 1:119–137

Blanchard EJ, Olney WW (2017) Globalization and human capital investment: export composition drives educational attainment. J Int Econ 106:165–183. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2017.03.004

Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8

Bravo-Ortega C, Benavente JM, González Á (2014) Innovation, exports, and productivity: learning and self-selection in Chile. Emerg Mark Financ Trade 50:68–95. https://doi.org/10.2753/REE1540-496X5001S105

Cadot O, Carrere C, Strauss-kahn V (2011) Export diversification: what’s behind the hump? Rev ofEconomics Stat 93:590–605

Cárdenas G, Suárez E, Romero H, Fajardo E (2019) Composición de importaciones y actividad económica: El caso de Colombia. Espacios 40:24

Carrasco CA, Tovar-García ED (2019) Determinantes del Balance Comercial Bilateral de México: Ingreso, Tipo de Cambio y Composición de las Exportaciones. Rev Finanz y Política Económica 11:1

Carroll P, Pol E, Robertson PL (2000) Classification of industries by level of technology: an appraisal and some implications. Prometh Crit Stud Innov 18:417–436. https://doi.org/10.1080/08109020020008523

Caselli F, Wilson DJ (2004) Importing technology. J Monet Econ 51:1–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.07.004

Del Prete D, Giovannetti G, Marvasi E (2017) Global value chains participation and productivity gains for North African firms. Rev World Econ 153:675–701. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-017-0292-2

Dennis A, Shepherd B (2011) Trade facilitation and export diversification. World Econ 34:101–122. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2010.01303.x

Dollar D, Kraay A (2004) Trade, growth, and poverty. Econ J 114:F22–F49. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.00186.x

Dornbusch R (1992) The case for trade liberalization in developing countries. J Econ Perspect 6:69–85. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.6.1.69

Dosi G, Roventini A, Russo E (2019) Endogenous growth and global divergence in a multi-country agent-based model. J Econ Dyn Control 101:101–129. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2019.02.005

Eaton J, Kortum S (2001) Trade in capital goods. Eur Econ Rev 45:1195–1235. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(00)00103-3

Ekananda M, Parlinggoman DJ (2017) The role of high-tech exports and of foreign direct investments (FDI) on economic growth. Eur Res Stud J 20:194–212

Fagerberg J, Lundvall B-A, Srholec M (2018) Global value chains, national innovation systems and economic development. Eur J Dev Res. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-0180147-2

Foster-McGregor N, Kaulich F, Stehrer R (2015) Global value chains in Africa. Maastricht, The Netherlands

Fosu AK (1990) Export composition and the impact of exports on economic growth of developing economies. Econ Lett 34:67–71. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(90)90183-2

Frankel JA, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89:379–399. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.379

Fujii G (2000) El comercio exterior manufacturero y los límites al crecimiento económico de México. Comer Exter Noviembre 1:1008–1014

Fujii G, Candaudap E, Gaona C (2005) Exportaciones, industria maquiladora y crecimiento económico en México a partir de la década de los noventa. Investig Económica 64:125–156

Ghatak S, Milner C, Utkulu U (1997) Exports, export composition and growth: cointegration and causality evidence for Malaysia. Appl Econ 29:213–223. https://doi.org/10.1080/000368497327272

Glaeser EL, La-Porta R, Lopez-De-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2004) Do institutions cause growth? J Econ Growth 9:271–303

Grossman GM, Helpman E (1990) Trade, innovation, and growth. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 80:86–91

Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Trade, knowledge spillovers, and growth. Eur Econ Rev 35:517–526. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(91)90153-A

Hagemejer J (2018) Trade and growth in the new member states: the role of global value chains. Emerg Mark Financ Trade 54:2630–2649. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496X.2017.1369878

Hagemejer J, Mućk J (2019) Export-led growth and its determinants: evidence from Central and Eastern European countries. World Econ 42:1994–2025. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12790

Haini H (2019) Examining the relationship between finance, institutions and economic growth: evidence from the ASEAN economies. Econ Chang Restruct. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-019-09257-5

Hatzichronoglou T (1997) Revision of the high-technology sector and product classification

Hausmann R, Hwang J, Rodrik D (2007) What you export matters. J Econ Growth 12:1–25. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-006-9009-4

Henn C, Papageorgiou C, Spatafora N (2013) Export quality in developing countries

Herrerias MJ, Orts V (2013) Capital goods imports and long-run growth: is the Chinese experience relevant to developing countries? J Policy Model 35:781–797. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2013.02.006

Herzer D, Nowak-Lehnmann DF (2006) What does export diversification do for growth? An econometric analysis. Appl Econ 38:1825–1838. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840500426983

Herzer D, Nowak-Lehmann F, Siliverstovs B (2006) Export-led growth in Chile: assessing the role of export composition in productivity growth. Dev Econ 44:306–328. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1746-1049.2006.00019.x

Hesse H (2009) Export diversification and economic growth. In: Newfarmer R, Shaw W, Walkenhorst P (eds) Breaking into new markets: emerging lessons for export diversification. The World Bank, Washington, pp 55–80

Hirsch S, Lev B (1971) Sales stabilization through export diversification. Rev Econ Stat 53:270. https://doi.org/10.2307/1937971

Im KS, Pesaran MH, Shin Y (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J Econom 115:53–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(03)00092-7

International Monetary Fund (2014) Sustaining long-run growth and macroeconomic stability in low-income countries—The role of structural transformation and diversification

Johnson RC (2014) Five facts about value-added exports and implications for macroeconomics and trade research. J Econ Perspect 28:119–142. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.28.2.119

Kim D-H, Lin S-C, Suen Y-B (2016) Trade, growth and growth volatility: new panel evidence. Int Rev Econ Financ 45:384–399. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2016.07.006

Krueger A (1974) The political economy of the rent-seeking society. Am Econ Rev 64:291–303

Kummritz V (2015) Global value chains: benefiting the domestic economy?

Lee J-W (1995) Capital goods imports and long-run growth. J Dev Econ 48:91–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(95)00015-1

Lewer JJ (2002) International trade composition and medium-run growth: evidence of a causal relationship. Int Trade J 16:295–317. https://doi.org/10.1080/08853900290090809

Maddala GS, Wu S (1999) A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a new simple test. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 61:631–652. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0084.0610s1631

Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107:407–437. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118477

Mazumdar J (1996) Do static gains from trade lead to medium-run growth? J Polit Econ 104:1328–1337. https://doi.org/10.1086/262062

Munir K, Javed Z (2018) Export composition and economic growth: evidence from South Asian countries. South Asian J Bus Stud 7:225–240. https://doi.org/10.1108/SAJBS-10-2017-0117

Mutreja P, Ravikumar B, Sposi M (2018) Capital goods trade, relative prices, and economic development. Rev Econ Dyn 27:101–122. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2017.11.003

Naito T (2017) An asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth. Econ Lett 158:80–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2017.06.016

Naudé W, Rossouw R (2011) Export diversification and economic performance: evidence from Brazil, China, India and South Africa. Econ Chang Restruct 44:99–134. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-010-9089-1

Palley TI (2012) The rise and fall of export-led growth. Investig Económica 71:141–161

Peneder M (2003) Industry classifications: aim, scope and techniques. J Ind Compet Trade 3:109–129. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1025434721292

Pierola MD, Fernandes AM, Farole T (2018) The role of imports for exporter performance in Peru. World Econ 41:550–572. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12524

Pistoresi B, Rinaldi A (2012) Exports, imports and growth. Explor Econ Hist 49:241–254. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2011.11.003

Raveh O, Reshef A (2016) Capital imports composition, complementarities, and the skill premium in developing countries. J Dev Econ 118:183–206. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2015.07.011

Rhoades SA (1993) The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index. Fed Reserv Bull 79:188–189

Rodil-Marzábal O (2018) La cara oculta del comercio de México con Estados Unidos. Comer Exter 13:8–14

Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037

Romer PM (1994) The origins of endogenous growth. J Econ Perspect 8:3–22

Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 71:135–158. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x

Sachs JD, Warner A (1995) Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1995:1–95. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534573

Santos-Paulino AU (2011) Trade specialization, export productivity and growth in Brazil, China, India, South Africa, and a cross section of countries. Econ Chang Restruct 44:75–97. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-010-9087-3

Saviotti PP, Frenken K (2008) Export variety and the economic performance of countries. J Evol Econ 18:201–218. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-007-0081-5

Saviotti PP, Pyka A (2013) The co-evolution of innovation, demand and growth. Econ Innov New Technol 22:461–482. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2013.768492

Sheridan BJ (2014) Manufacturing exports and growth: when is a developing country ready to transition from primary exports to manufacturing exports? J Macroecon 42:1–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2014.06.002

Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94

Srholec M (2007) High-tech exports from developing countries: a symptom of technology spurts or statistical illusion? Rev World Econ 143:227–255. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-007-0106-z

Tovar-García ED (2018) Does the share of crude petroleum and natural gas in exports increase total exports? The Russian case. World Econ Int Relations 62:30–35. https://doi.org/10.20542/0131-2227-2018-62-6-30-35

Tovar-García ED, Carrasco CA (2019a) The balance of payments and Russian economic growth. HSE Econ J 23:524–541. https://doi.org/10.17323/1813-8691-2019-23-4-524-541

Tovar-García ED, Carrasco CA (2019b) Export and import composition as determinants of bilateral trade in goods: evidence from Russia. Post-Communist Econ 31:530–546. https://doi.org/10.1080/14631377.2018.1557913

Toye J (2003) The Origins and Interpretation of the Prebisch-Singer Thesis. Hist Polit Econ 35:437–467. https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-35-3-437

Turco AL (2012) Economic growth and the role of trade in intermediates. Econ Bull 32:1–20

Vogiatzoglou K (2019) Export composition and long-run economic growth impact: a cointegration analysis for ASEAN ‘Latecomer’ Economies. Margin J Appl Econ Res 13:168–191. https://doi.org/10.1177/0973801018812571

Wacziarg R, Welch KH (2008) Trade liberalization and growth: new evidence. World Bank Econ Rev 22:187–231. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhn007

Wierts P, Van Kerkhoff H, De Haan J (2014) Composition of exports and export performance of Eurozone countries. J Common Mark Stud 52:928–941. https://doi.org/10.1111/jcms.12114

Download references

Acknowledgements

Comments from the Editor and two anonymous reviewers are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Departamento de Economía, Universidad de Monterrey (UDEM), Av. Ignacio Morones Prieto 4500 Pte, 66238, San Pedro Garza García, N.L., Mexico

Carlos A. Carrasco

Universidad Panamericana, Escuela de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales, Álvaro del Portillo 49, 45010, Zapopan, Jalisco, Mexico

Edgar Demetrio Tovar-García

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlos A. Carrasco .

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Carrasco, C.A., Tovar-García, E.D. Trade and growth in developing countries: the role of export composition, import composition and export diversification. Econ Change Restruct 54 , 919–941 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-020-09291-8

Download citation

Received : 15 July 2019

Accepted : 27 July 2020

Published : 03 August 2020

Issue Date : November 2021

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-020-09291-8

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Economic growth
  • Export composition
  • Export diversification
  • Import composition
  • Developing countries

JEL Classification

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here .

Loading metrics

Open Access

Peer-reviewed

Research Article

Effects of COVID-19 on trade flows: Measuring their impact through government policy responses

Contributed equally to this work with: Javier Barbero, Juan José de Lucio, Ernesto Rodríguez-Crespo

Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Resources, Software, Supervision, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

Affiliation Joint Research Centre (JRC), European Commission, Seville, Andalucía, Spain

Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Resources, Software, Supervision, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

* E-mail: [email protected]

Affiliation Department of Economic Structure and Development Economics, Universidad de Alcalá de Henares, Alcalá de Henares, Madrid, Spain

ORCID logo

Affiliation Department of Economic Structure and Development Economics, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Madrid, Spain

  • Javier Barbero, 
  • Juan José de Lucio, 
  • Ernesto Rodríguez-Crespo

PLOS

  • Published: October 13, 2021
  • https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356
  • Peer Review
  • Reader Comments

Table 1

This paper examines the impact of COVID-19 on bilateral trade flows using a state-of-the-art gravity model of trade. Using the monthly trade data of 68 countries exporting across 222 destinations between January 2019 and October 2020, our results are threefold. First, we find a greater negative impact of COVID-19 on bilateral trade for those countries that were members of regional trade agreements before the pandemic. Second, we find that the impact of COVID-19 is negative and significant when we consider indicators related to governmental actions. Finally, this negative effect is more intense when exporter and importer country share identical income levels. In the latter case, the highest negative impact is found for exports between high-income countries.

Citation: Barbero J, de Lucio JJ, Rodríguez-Crespo E (2021) Effects of COVID-19 on trade flows: Measuring their impact through government policy responses. PLoS ONE 16(10): e0258356. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356

Editor: Stefan Cristian Gherghina, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, ROMANIA

Received: April 12, 2021; Accepted: September 26, 2021; Published: October 13, 2021

Copyright: © 2021 Barbero et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License , which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

Data Availability: The data underlying the results presented in the study are available from UN Comtrade ( https://comtrade.un.org ), the Centre d'Études Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales (CEPII) Gravity database ( http://www.cepii.fr/cepii/en/bdd_modele/presentation.asp?id=8 ) and from Our World in Data COVID-19 Git Hub repository ( https://github.com/owid/covid-19-data/tree/master/public/data ). The three datasets are publicly available for all researchers. Merging the three datasets and following the steps described in the “Model description and estimation strategy” section readers can replicate the results of this manuscript.

Funding: de Lucio and Rodríguez-Crespo thank financial support from Universidad de Alcalá de Henares (UAH) and Banco Santander through research project COVID-19 UAH 2019/00003/016/001/007. De Lucio also thanks financial support from Comunidad de Madrid and UAH (ref: EPU-INV/2020/006 and H2019/HUM5761).

Competing interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

Introduction

The world is facing an unexpected recession due to the disruption of the COVID-19 pandemic in the global economy. In parallel with the consequences of the 2008–2009 crisis, international trade has once again collapsed. World trade volumes decreased by 21% between March and April 2020, while during the previous crisis the highest monthly drop was 18%, between September and October 2008. Cumulative export growth rate for the period December 2019– March 2020 was -7%, while for the period July 2008 –February 2009 it was -0,8%. The 2020 downturn was less prolonged than that caused by the latter crisis. Trade volumes in August 2020 only showed a 3% decrease compared to March 2020. The World Trade Organization (WTO) estimated that international merchandise trade volumes fell by 9.2% in 2020, a figure similar in magnitude to the global financial crisis of 2008–2009, although factors such as the economic context, the origins of the crisis and the transmission channels are deemed to be very distinct from the previous crisis [ 1 ].

Due to its rapid propagation, a proper evaluation of the economic impacts of COVID-19 crisis is not only desirable but challenging if the aim is to mitigate uncertainty [ 2 ]. The COVID-19 crisis has its origins in the policy measures adopted to combat the health crisis, while the 2008–2009 crisis had economic roots contingent on financially related issues. At the current time, the collapse of international trade has been driven by the voluntary and mandatory confinement measures imposed on world trade. We aim to analyse the impact of said confinement measures on trade. Estimating COVID-19 impacts on trade would shed light on the cost of confinement measures and the evolution and forecast of bilateral trade.

From an empirical point of view, we resort to [ 3 ], who use quarterly data for the period 2003–2005 in order to analyse the impact of the SARS epidemic on firms. They show that regions with higher transmission of SARS experienced lower import and export growth compared to those in the unaffected regions. The propagation of a virus resembles natural disasters, with both interpreted as external non-economic based shocks, the effects of which have been addressed already in the literature (e.g., [ 4 – 9 ]).

Another strand of the literature directly analyses the effects of the COVID-19 pandemic on global trade in terms of the transmission mechanism of the shock: demand, supply and global supply chains. Some authors argue that demand factors have played an important role in explaining the shock [ 10 , 11 ] conclude that both shocks (demand and supply) are present in the crisis [ 1 ] highlight the role of global value chains in the transmission of shocks [ 12 ] focus on supply chain disruptions and reveal that those sectors with large exposure to intermediate goods imports from China contracted more than other sectors [ 13 ]. Focus on the role of global supply chains on the GDP growth for 64 countries during the COVID-19 pandemic and show that one quarter of the total downturn is due to global supply chains transmission. They also conclude that in general global supply chains, make countries more resilient to pandemic-induced contractions in labour supply. Finally, the collapse in trade can also be considered as a trade-induced effect caused by economic recessions (e.g., [ 14 – 16 ]) and may also be associated with the impact of COVID-19.

During the current wave of globalization, time lags in synchronizing business cycles between countries are reduced significantly in terms of the intensity of trade relationships [ 17 ]. Find that business cycle synchronization increases when countries trade more with each other [ 18 ]. Show that bilateral trade intensity has a sizeable positive, statistically significant, and robust impact on synchronization. These results are in line with [ 19 ], who finds that greater trade intensity increases business cycle synchronization, especially in country pairs with a free trade agreement and among industrial country pairs. Our paper provides prima facie evidence that this relationship also holds during pandemic-related trade shocks.

We contribute to the literature by integrating monthly data for a trade analysis of 68 countries, 31 of which are classified as high-income. We additionally focus on differential effects between high-income and low- and middle-income countries. This paper aims to shed light on the impact of COVID-19 on exports by means of an integrated approach for a significant number of countries, thereby avoiding an individual analysis of a single country or region that could potentially be affected by idiosyncratic shocks. Given the existence of substantial differences in trade performance and containment measures exhibited by countries and trade partners and attributable in part to their income, we also study whether the impact of COVID-19 on trade differs in terms of income levels. To the best of our knowledge, both questions, the integrated impact of confinement measures and the income related effects, remain unexplored in previous studies.

A proper analysis of ex-post trade impacts related to COVID-19 requires a suitable and fruitful methodology. Gravity models can be helpful in achieving this goal, since they have recently started to incorporate monthly trade data into the analyses, albeit with empirical evidence that is still scarce and far from conclusive [ 8 , 20 , 21 ]. At the same time, several methodological issues need to be resolved adequately when using gravity models [ 22 ]. Resorting to monthly data may pose several advantages in terms of accomplishing our research goals and exploiting the explanatory power exhibited by gravity models and monthly country confinement measures. First, the data reflect monthly variations and allow us to better capture any differential effects arising across countries. Second, annual trade data do not capture the short-run impact of shocks that occur very rapidly, something which a monthly time span can achieve. Monthly data can pick up any rapid movements associated with COVID-19 measures and allow for differential shocks in relation to months and countries. This is particularly relevant given the growing importance of nowcasting and short-term analysis techniques required nowadays for an understanding of world economy dynamics. Finally, monthly data can explain the relative importance of demand and supply shocks during the course of the trade crisis.

We collect monthly trade data for 68 countries ( S1 Table ), which exported to 222 destinations between January 2019 and October 2020. Using state-of-the-art estimation techniques for trade-related gravity models, our results are threefold. First, we reveal a negative impact of COVID-19 on trade that holds across specifications. Second, we obtain results that do not vary substantially when considering different governmental measures. Finally, our results show that the greatest negative COVID-19 impact occurs for exports within groups (high-income countries and low-middle-income countries), but not between groups. These findings are robust to different tests resulting from the introduction of lagging explanatory variables, alternative trade flows (exports vs imports as the dependent variable) or COVID-19 impact measures (independent variables such as stringency index or the number of reported deaths per million population).

Literature review on COVID-19 and trade

The specific literature covering the COVID-19 induced effects on trade can be catalogued as flourishing and burgeoning, but also as incipient and inconclusive at the current time. Some studies have addressed the impact of the health-related crisis on trade. The first strand of literature analyses the effects of previous pandemics by emphasizing asymmetric impacts across sectors. Using the quarterly transaction-level trade data of all Chinese firms in 2003 [ 3 ], estimate the effects of the first SARS pandemic on trade in that year. They find that (i) Chinese regions with a local transmission of SARS experienced a lower decline in trade margins, and (ii) the trade of more skilled and capital-intensive products was less affected by the pandemic.

Despite data being scarce, other studies focus on the current COVID-19 trade shock but are usually restricted to specific countries. For the case of Switzerland [ 23 ], combine weekly and monthly trade data, for the lockdown between mid-March and the end of July. They use goods information disaggregated by product and trade partner. They find that: (i) During lockdown Swiss trade fell 11% compared to the same period of 2019, and this trade shock proved more profound than the previous trade shock in 2009, (ii) contraction in Swiss exports seems to be correlated with the number of COVID-19 cases in importing countries, but at the same time, Swiss imports are related to the stringency of government measures in the exporter country (iii) for the case of products, only pharmaceutical and chemical products remained resilient to the trade shock and (iv) the pandemic negatively affected the demand and supply sides of foreign trade [ 24 ]. Use a gravity model and focus on exports from China for the period January 2019 to December 2020. They find a negative effect of COVID-19 on trade, but said effect is largely attenuated for medical goods and products that entail working from home.

For the case of Spain [ 10 ], find that for the period between January and July 2020, stringency in containment measures at the destination countries decreased Spanish exports, while imports did not succumb to such a sharp decline. Finally [ 25 ], extends the discussion of the Spanish case to analyse the impact of COVID-19 on trade in goods and services, corroborating the existence of a negative effect. He finds a more pronounced decline for trade in services, due to the importance of tourism in the Spanish economy.

Other studies have provided additional evidence by considering a larger sample of countries. Using monthly bilateral trade data of EU member states covering the period from June 2015 to May 2020 [ 20 ], use a gravity model framework to highlight the role of chain forward linkages for the transmission of Covid-19 demand shocks. They explain that when the pandemic spread and more prominent measures were taken, not only did demand decrease further, but labour supply shortage and production halted [ 21 ]. Find a negative impact of COVID-19 on trade growth for a sample of 28 countries and their most relevant trade partners. Their findings suggest that COVID-19 has affected sectoral trade growth negatively by decreasing countries’ participations in Global Value Chains from the beginning of the pandemic to June 2020 [ 26 ]. Analyse the impact of COVID-19 on trade for a larger sample of countries, focusing on export flows for 35 reporting countries and 250 partner countries between January and August in both 2019 and 2020. However, they restrict, their study exclusively to trade in medical goods and find that an increase in COVID-19 stringency leads to lower exports of medical products. Finally [ 27 ], use maritime trade shipping data from January to June 2020 for different countries, such as Australia, China, Germany, Malaysia, New Zealand, South Africa, United States, United Kingdom, and Vietnam. By applying the automatic identification system methodology to observational data, they obtain pronounced declines in trade, albeit the effect is different for each country.

Surprisingly, little attention has been paid to the impacts of COVID-19 on trade for different country income levels and we find several reasons to consider this issue as important. First, the role of trade costs is important, as the latter are related to economic policy and direct policy instruments (e.g., tariffs) are less relevant compared to other components [ 28 ]. According to [ 29 ], differences are expected in trade between high-,low- and middle-income countries due to the composition of trade costs: information, transport, and transaction costs seem to be more important for trade between high-income countries, while trade policy and regulatory differences better explain trade between low- and middle-income countries. The second reason is related to the composition of products, given that average skills in making a product are more intensive in high-income countries resulting in increasing complexity of the products traded compared to low- and middle-income countries [ 30 ]. Accordingly, specific product categories incorporate more embedded knowledge and their production may require engaging in a global production network with multiple countries. However, it has been alleged that participation of countries in global value chains depends on their income levels due to the objectives pursued: high-income countries focus on achieving growth and sustainability, while low- and middle-income countries seek to attract foreign direct investment and increase their economic upgrading [ 31 ]. Third, it is found that low-income countries present a lower share of jobs that can be done at home [ 32 ], rendering them more sensitive to lockdowns that affect services. Finally, due to the paucity of health supplies to mitigate COVID-19, as certain healthcare commodities may not be affordable for certain low-income countries [ 33 ]. Consequently, the effect of COVID-19 on the global economy may be more pronounced for those countries with fewer healthcare resources and impacts on trade do not constitute an exception.

Due to the reasons mentioned above, we expect different countries’ responses to trade shocks induced by COVID-19 depending on their income levels, but this issue remains largely unexplored by the academic literature. The only exception is [ 34 ], but they reduce their analysis to COVID-19 impacts on trade concerning Commonwealth countries. Using the period from January 2019 to November 2020, they find ambivalent evidence: an increase in the number of COVID-19 cases in low-income countries reduced Commonwealth exports, but an identical scenario in high-income countries boosted their export flows.

All these findings are summarized as follows. In Table 1 , we present a compilation of studies using monthly data that feature the impact of COVID-19 on trade.

thumbnail

  • PPT PowerPoint slide
  • PNG larger image
  • TIFF original image

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.t001

It is also worth noting that the main shock started in March 2020, when most countries closed their borders and implemented lockdown measures. Accordingly, further analysis of COVID-19 impacts on trade requires periods with high frequency, such as monthly data, in order to deliver satisfactory results. Apart from the aforementioned studies in the context of COVID-19 research, to the best of our knowledge, monthly data are scarcely used in gravity models. They have been used either in the context of trade preferences [ 35 , 36 ] or, more recently, to study the impact of natural disasters on trade [ 8 ].

Additionally, we aim to provide evidence concerning the COVID-19 effects on trade at country level, without restricting our research to either specific countries or territories, or, specific trade flows, such as intermediate goods. Since the COVID-19 crisis is still ongoing, it is also necessary to incorporate the most recent and updated time spans to provide policy recommendations aligned with the business cycle. We intend to analyse whether COVID-19 impacts on trade have affected the world economy from a global perspective. This analysis will allow us to distinguish different impacts in terms of levels of economic development, which to the best of our knowledge, remain largely unexplored by the academic literature.

Empirical analysis

This section is organized into three separate sub-sections. First, we describe the empirical model and the estimation strategy. Second, we report information on data issues. Finally, we cover country policy responses to COVID-19.

Model description and estimation strategy

For the purpose of accomplishing our research objectives, we resort to a bilateral trade gravity model, which has progressively become the reference methodology for analysing the causal impacts of specific variables on trade (e.g., [ 22 , 37 – 40 ]; among other scholars).

research paper on import and export

Where subscripts i , j and m refer to exporter and importer country and month, respectively. COVID m is a control variable that takes value 1 for a COVID-19 trade shock, after March 2020, and 0 otherwise. DIST ij is the geographical distance between exporter and importer country. CONTIG ij is a control variable that takes value 1 when exporter and importer country are adjacent and 0 otherwise. COMLANG ij is a control variable that takes value 1 when exporter and importer country share a common language and 0 otherwise. COLONY ij is a control variable that takes value 1 when exporter and importer country share past colonial linkages and 0 otherwise. RTA ij is a control variable that takes value 1 when exporter and importer country have a regional trade agreement in force and 0 otherwise. In addition to these explanatory variables, we also consider other control variables to capture omitted factors. φ im and γ jm are exporter-month and importer-month fixed effects, respectively. Finally, ε ijm stands for the error term.

The logic behind including these variables is found in the literature, and the explanation is provided as follows: COVID-19-related variables are introduced to estimate the impact of the current COVID-19-shock on trade, since it is expected to be detrimental (e.g., [ 3 , 23 ]). Governmental actions are expected to reduce the duration and magnitude of COVID-19 shock by facilitating a smoother transition to a post-pandemic scenario while generating an economic downturn in the short-run due to the limitations of economic activity and the increase in government expenditure. Adjacency and distance relate to the geographical impacts on trade, given the great influence exerted by geography on trade patterns [ 43 ]. Adjacency is included due to the existence of a border effect, where countries tend to concentrate their trade flows with nearby trade partners [ 41 , 44 ], so that higher adjacency leads to increasing trade flows. The reasons to include distance in gravity models stem from the early contributions [ 45 ]. Countries prefer to trade with less distant trade partners, so that a negative coefficient is expected. Colonial linkages and common language respond to the flourishing literature on the impact of institutions on trade, where the latter play a key role in reducing trade costs and facilitating trade (e.g., [ 46 , 47 ]; among others). Finally, regional trade agreements have multiplied exponentially in the context of globalization and trade liberalization, so that they contribute to decreasing trade costs and enhancing trade [ 48 , 49 ].

Exporter-month and importer-month fixed effects are included to comply with multilateral resistance terms (MRTs), which are related to third-country impacts on the bilateral relationship. They are considered as a pivotal element of modern gravity equations [ 41 ]. According to the structural gravity literature, the omission of such aforementioned MRTs is expected to lead to inconsistent and biased outcomes [ 22 ].

Concerning the previous gravity specification, it is important to highlight that our baseline gravity Eq ( 1 ) does not contain GDP, which is considered a fundamental variable in the seminal gravity models because it measures country size [ 45 ]. The omission of GDP is intentional due to several reasons: (i) GDP variables tend to vary quarterly or yearly and (ii) the inclusion of exporter-month and importer-month fixed effects are perfectly collinear with GDP, so that these control variables will capture its effects on trade.

research paper on import and export

Eq ( 2 ) introduces some novelties in relation to the previous Eq ( 1 ). First, by interacting the COVID-19 variable with the control variable for regional trade agreements we can compute the impact of COVID-19 on trade by assuming that countries with regional trade agreements affect this empirical relationship. Thus we assess whether COVID-19 impacts on trade are more (less) profound for these countries with (without) previous regional trade agreements. We sum 1 to the variable before taking the logs to avoid losing the observations before the COVID started. This strategy responds to the strands of literature that acknowledge the role of international trade as a driver of business cycle synchronization (e.g., [ 51 , 52 ]) and, more specifically, that regional trade agreements may be behind the transmission of shocks across countries (e.g., [ 19 , 53 , 54 ]). In particular, we follow [ 26 ] approach since the interaction between COVID-19 variables and regional trade agreements allows us to study the heterogeneous impacts of COVID-19 on trade by bringing economic linkages into the discussion.

Another advantage is that interacting an explanatory variable with a control variable may also relieve us from endogeneity issues, as shown by [ 55 ]. In particular, COVID-19 impacts on trade may be driven by omitted variable bias. However, this comes at the cost of not interpreting exporter and importer impacts simultaneously, as both coefficients become symmetric and only one of them can be interpreted, as shown by [ 56 ] and [ 57 ] when studying the impact of institutions on trade using gravity equations at country and regional level, respectively.

Eq ( 2 ) also considers a third set of fixed effects, which are exporter-importer pair effects denoted by η ij . Considering pair effects in the gravity equation as an explanatory variable may pose the advantage of mitigating the estimation from endogenous impacts induced by time-invariant determinants (e.g., [ 58 , 59 ]) and hence may improve the empirical specification. Three-way fixed effects, constituted by pair, exporter-month and importer-month fixed effects, have become the spotlight in gravity specifications assessing the impact of natural disasters on trade, even for those scholars using monthly data, such as [ 8 ].

Finally, we acknowledge that the simultaneous inclusion of such three-way fixed effects, requires large amounts of data in order to carry out the estimation procedure. For this reason, sophisticated PPML estimation commands have recently been developed for gravity equation estimations, so that they can include a high number of dimensional fixed effects and run relatively fast in contrast to previous existing commands [ 60 , 61 ].

Our sample covers a set of 68 countries exporting across 222 destinations, between January 2019 and October 2020 with 31 of these exporters classified as high-income countries. Due to the specific monthly nature of COVID-19 shock, we rely on monthly bilateral trade flows gathered from UN Comtrade. Trade data were extracted on the 15 of February 2021, using the UN Comtrade Bulk Download service. According to the degree of availability of monthly trade flows for countries, our analysis covers aggregate trade flows. For those observations with missing trade flows, we conveniently follow previous studies that suggest that missing trade flows can be completed with zeros, [ 50 , 62 ].

Variables related to the COVID-19 government response have been taken from the systematic dataset of policy measures elaborated by the Blavatnik School of Government at Oxford University [ 63 ]. These indices refer to government response, health measures, stringency, and economic measures. Their composition and implications are described more broadly in the following sections.

The rest of the variables, institutional and geographical, are gathered from the Centre d’Études Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales (CEPII) Gravity database [ 64 ]. S1 and S2 Tables show the list of countries and the main descriptive statistics, respectively.

Policy responses to COVID-19: equal or unequal?

Once COVID-19 spread across a significant number of countries, they were urged to implement policy actions of response. For this reason, several indicators were built to measuring countries´ governmental response to COVID-19. As mentioned previously, the set of policy indicators developed by [ 63 ] constitutes the most noteworthy approach for measuring countries´ policy responses. The four indicators are described as follows:

  • Stringency index (upper left chart, Fig 1 ) contains the degree of lockdown policies to control the pandemic via restricting people´s social outcomes. The index is built using data on the closure in education (schools and universities), public transport and workspaces, the cancellation of public events, limits on gatherings, restrictions in internal movements, and orders to confine at home.
  • Economic Support index (upper right chart, Fig 1 ) includes measures related to public expenditure, such as income support to people who lose their jobs or cannot work, debt relief to households, fiscal measures, and spending to other countries.
  • Containment and Health index (lower left chart, Fig 1 ) combines lockdown measures with health policies, such as the openness of the testing policy to all the population with symptoms or asymptomatic, the extent of the contact tracing, the policy on mandatory use of facial coverings, and monetary investments in healthcare and in vaccines.
  • Overall Government Response index (lower right chart, Fig 1 ) collects all governments’ responses to COVID-19 by assessing whether they have become stronger or weaker. This index combines all the variables of the containment and health index and the economic support index.

thumbnail

Source: own elaboration from [ 63 ]. Note: each point represents a country, and the concentration of countries with similar values produces darker areas. Additionally, the mean and 95% confidence bands are represented.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.g001

These indices vary from 0 to 100, with a higher value indicating stronger country measures in response to COVID-19. As these indicators are collected daily, we convert them to monthly averages. The evolution of the four indicators is presented in Fig 1 , where each point represents a country and the concentration of countries with similar values produces darker areas. Additionally, the mean and 95% confidence bands are represented. We pay special attention to differences between high-income and low- and middle-income countries, in line with our research objectives.

Stringency reaches its maximum in April 2020 when the first wave reaches its peak in most countries. Since then, restrictions have been slowly lifted but started to increase again after the summer in high-income countries, coinciding with the beginning of the second wave.

Economic support increased rapidly in March and April and remains stable, with high-income countries granting more economic support to the population than low- and middle-income countries. The economic support variable identifies significant differences between high-income and low- and middle-income countries during the whole period.

The containment and health index and the overall government response index, present a similar pattern regarding income levels. However, we observe that low- and middle-income countries relaxed the measures from April 2021 onwards, whereas high-income countries did so in July 2021. In any case, the countries analysed show significant variability in all the indices, as indicated by the estimates made in the following section.

To sum up, we find that in low- and middle-income countries, pandemic measures have been slightly stricter than in high-income ones, as the values of their COVID-19 policy responses indices are higher for all cases except for the economic support index. The greater availability of resources in high-income countries to control the pandemic explains this difference.

Fig 2 displays the evaluation of total monthly exports in 2020, relative to January 2020, by income level for our sample of exporting countries. We observe the big decline in exports between March and April mentioned previously. In fact, the observed magnitude of trade decline as a consequence of COVID-19 is identical to the previous global recession, but contractions in GDP and trade flows are more profound at the current stage [ 65 ]. However, we observe that high-income countries have gradually been recovering their export flows, revealing a larger degree of resilience and how economic support policies might have helped them in recovering economic activity. In particular, greater firm engagement in trade because of previous global recession may be beneficial, as they have been able to recover in a shorter period of time from this new contraction in GDP due to the openness to foreign markets [ 66 ]. Find that net firm entry in export markets contributed less to export growth during the Great Trade Collapse, between 2008 and 2013, than continuing exporters. Export capacity to foreign markets in order to counteract the negative impact of local demand shocks is illustrated by [ 67 ] for the specific case of Spain.

thumbnail

Source: own elaboration using UN Comtrade trade data.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.g002

We acknowledge that policy responses differ by country, as the impacts of COVID-19 have been strongly unequal for countries due to several reasons. First, countries have reported differences in the number of deaths, mainly attributable to the population composition. There is an increasing number of elder populations in a significant number of high-income OECD countries [ 68 ] and this group is the most vulnerable to COVID-19 (e.g., [ 69 ]).

At the same time, countries have also implemented trade policy actions to mitigate the influence of COVID-19 on the global economy. For the sake of brevity and in line with the aim of the article, we only consider the trade policy response. Readers interested in analyzing a complete set of economic policy responses (i.e., budgetary and/or monetary) to COVID-19 are entitled to check the International Monetary Fund (IMF) Policy Tracker at https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/imf-and-covid19/Policy-Responses-to-COVID-19 .

We focus on the corresponding period coincident with our sample, but further trade policy actions have been implemented after this period because of the increasing number of cases related to COVID-19 in subsequent waves. They can be checked at the IMF Policy Tracker previously reported, which is updated regularly [ 70 ]. Summarizes the major stylized facts during the first nine months of the pandemic. First, there was a noticeable rise in trade policy activism consisting mainly of export controls and import liberalization measures with strong cross-country variation. Second, this activism was reported to vary by country and products, where medical and food products experimented a substantial overall increase in their demand from February 2020. Third, we observe a further trade liberalization process after May 2020, where the number of liberalization measures exceeded the number of trade restrictions in medical products.

Such cross-country variation in trade policy response aligns with our expectations since, as mentioned previously, trade specialization differs by country. Accordingly, their sensitivity to the growing demand for food and medical products may vary substantially. For this reason, some countries were more resilient to COVID-19 trade shocks than other countries, as shown by the decreases observed in their trade flows. To this end, we compare trade drops for the most affected countries relative to January 2020 and their governmental response, from May 2020 to October 2020. As described by [ 70 ], countries experienced a substantial relaxation in most of their trade measures in May 2020.

For the ten countries with the largest trade drop evidence is ambivalent. For the sake of brevity, we have omitted the data concerning each country and provide a general overview. Data is available from the authors upon request to the corresponding author and can be obtained from the UN Comtrade database. On the one hand, four high-income (Macao, Mauritius, Portugal, and Slovakia) and six middle-income countries (El Salvador, Mexico, Montenegro, Guyana, Egypt, and Romania) were among the most affected countries in May 2020, with El Salvador registering the highest level of governmental response. Trade relative to January 2020 ranges from 51 to 69 percent in this period. On the other hand, we find that the number of high-income countries increased to six in October 2020 but, at the same time, differences in governmental response decreased their observed variance. Israel registered the highest level of governmental response during this month. In this case, relative trade ranges from 76 to 102, corroborating the previous finding that countries recovered rapidly from this trade shock. To sum up, despite differences in governmental response due to the impact of COVID-19 by countries, recovery can be alleged to follow similar patterns for the most affected countries.

This section is organized into three separate sub-sections. First, we present a benchmark analysis, and afterwards we show the main results obtained for the four different COVID-19 government policy response indices. Finally, we review whether COVID-19 impacts differ by levels of economic development.

Benchmark analysis

This section reviews four specifications of the gravity equation: Column (I) in Table 2 includes the COVID-19 binary variable without interactions and only including exporter and importer fixed effects. Column (II) departs from Eq ( 2 ) but introduces exporter-month and importer-month fixed effects and, finally, column (III) adds pair fixed effects to the specification showed in column (II). For this robustness analysis, we use COVID m variable, which takes value 1 from March 2020, when several countries worldwide implemented lockdown measures, and 0 otherwise.

thumbnail

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.t002

The coefficients shown in column (I) may be biased because the specification does not accurately capture those factors related to MRTs and structural gravity. We hence move on to the alternative specification considered in columns (II) and (III), where we choose column (3) because it corresponds to Eq ( 2 ) and solves limitations in the baseline Eq ( 1 ).

Alternative specifications show an unequivocal detrimental effect of COVID-19 shock on trade. While the magnitude of the COVID-19 coefficient in column (I) is larger, -0.204, the size decreases when we move to our baseline specification in column (III), where we interact with the RTA variable, with an estimated coefficient of -0.050 when we include pair fixed-effects. The rest of the variables show the expected coefficients according to the theoretical insights and projections of gravity models.

Results by COVID-19 government policy responses indices

We now estimate our results introducing the four COVID-19 government response indices using Eq ( 2 ), as governments in countries more affected by the pandemic are expected to response with stringency, health, and economic support measures. Table 3 shows that the effect of COVID-19 on trade is negative and significant for all the variables considered. We agree with the existing literature on the negative impact of COVID-19 on trade (e.g. [ 21 , 23 ]); and also with the negative impact of previous pandemics [ 3 ]. We also find that results do not vary substantially across indices related to COVID-19, as they range between -0.009, for containment and health measures, and -0.012 for economic support. Although estimated parameters are not statistically different from each other, this might indicate that countries demanding more support to boost their economies have been the most affected ones by the COVID-19 trade shock. We also test our results using the traditional variable of COVID-19 reported deaths per million population as impact measure of the pandemic by country. Results, available under request, show no relevant variation to those presented in the article, which might be considered as an additional robustness test of the results presented.

thumbnail

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.t003

Our results suggest that COVID-19 may be detrimental to trade flows for those countries engaged in previous regional trade agreements compared to the countries that were not members of these agreements, as shown by the result of interacting these variables. However, interaction terms fail to reflect that those countries not participating in regional trade agreements were not affected by COVID-19, given the large set of existing possibilities of trade integration between countries. Furthermore, these countries could have been expanding their trade flows via preferential trade agreements, which are less restrictive than regional trade agreements.

Although the estimated elasticity may mistakenly appear low, it reflects a large elasticity of trade to COVID-19, given the observed change in the four indicators under consideration. For instance, the overall government response indicator increases, on average, from 3.16 to 70.09 from February to April 2020. This change corresponded to a 2,155% increase in the government response indicator that, multiplied by the estimated elasticity of -0.010, results in a sharp decrease in export flows of around 21%. The explanation may be twofold. On the one hand, the COVID-19 trade shock may be expected to be less dampening for the economy in comparison to the trade shock induced by the global financial crisis [ 23 ], as we highlighted previously. On the other hand, the COVID-19 trade shock is still ongoing and it may be necessary to include results for the second wave commencing September 2020.

We include two additional robustness tests. First, in S3 Table we show our results with lagged independent variables, in order to check whether there exist non-contemporary impacts of COVID-19 on trade. Our results show that the estimated coefficients remain significant and with greater values than those presented in Table 3 . Second, in S4 Table we consider the estimations for import trade flows as the dependent variable. The reason for including imports responds to [ 71 ] suggestion of using mirrored datasets, given that import trade flows are more subject to trade barriers than exports. In contrast to import trade regimes, most export trade regimes tend to be free and do not require additional documents or licenses to trade the goods. Results remain invariant in relation to those presented in Table 3 and S3 Table .

Results by levels of economic development

Finally, we complement the results by analysing whether COVID-19 impacts on trade depend on the levels of economic development of exporter and importer countries, distinguishing between high, low and middle-income importers, we follow the last version of the World Bank´s classification. These results are shown in Table 4 , where each cell contains the estimated coefficient and robust standard error for a different estimation of the COVID-19 government response indicators in a PPML regression that includes exporter-month, importer-month, and pair fixed effects. For instance, column (I) presents results for trade between high income countries, where the first row shows the estimated parameter for our reference equation, in line with column (4) in Table 1 . The following four rows correspond to the estimated parameters in Table 2 for COVID-19 related variables. Results with lagged independent variables, presented in S5 Table , show that estimated coefficients remain statistically significant and higher than those presented in Table 3 .

thumbnail

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.t004

We find that the COVID-19 effect on trade remains negative, but it seems to be inversely related to the income levels of the importer country. While the COVID-2019 dummy variable registers the highest negative impact, -0.103 for exports between high-income countries, (see column (I)), it is -0.055 between low-and middle-income countries, (see column (II)). The greater effect of the pandemic among integrated countries is in line with the results obtained by [ 20 ]. The effect found by [ 34 ] is the opposite, as COVID-19 in high-income countries spurs Commonwealth countries´ trade. However, their analysis focuses on a selected group of countries and distinguishes product categories so that the greater demand for medical products during the pandemic can explain these results. This fact reinforces the importance of including many countries in the sample since we can expect substantial differences in cross-country variation. We also find no significant effect of COVID-19 on the trade from exports of high-income to low-income countries in column (III) and a positive effect of exports from low-income to high-income in column (IV). These results remain similar when using lagged independent variables, presented in S5 Table . As robustness tests we include in S6 Table estimations for import trade flows. Results also remain invariant in relation to those presented in S3 Table .

These differences, within similar income groups and between groups, could be explained by the following. It is expected that countries more integrated into global supply chains and with greater business cycle synchronization are the most affected by trade collapse. We find that the existence of cross-country differences in capabilities is relevant since they determine countries’ comparative advantage [ 72 ]. In this context, high-income countries tend to be associated with exports of high-quality goods since they charge higher prices [ 73 ] and require larger amounts of skills to produce these goods [ 74 ]. Hence, the set of products exported between high-income countries may be related to goods with a higher degree of economic complexity, which exhibit a greater degree of resilience to economic shocks. This difference may also be explained by the higher demand for medical products by high-income countries, since the first COVID-19 wave starting in February 2020 reached this group of countries first.

We find a marginally significant positive effect for exports from low- and middle-income countries to high-income countries. This shows that countries belonging to this income group might have found an opportunity to supply the high-income countries’ markets, with whom they have regional trade agreements, these proving most affected by COVID-19 during the months in our sample. Low and middle-income countries are indeed progressively increasing their gains from trade because of greater exposure to globalization [ 75 ]; and this growth of trade flows from low and middle- income countries to high-income countries corroborates this evidence. Finally, not all kinds of products have been affected in the same magnitude. Evidence for outdoor goods can be found in [ 76 ]. Domestic consumption products, such as food, had a better performance during the pandemic, and low-income countries specializing in exporting these sorts of goods to high-income countries might have increased their exports to high -income countries.

Conclusions

In this study, we shed light on how the current COVID-19 crisis affects trade flows for the world economy during the first wave of the pandemic. We apply a PPML estimator with three sets of fixed effects in consistency with the recent literature on gravity models. Using monthly trade data for a sample of 68 countries, we find a negative impact of COVID-19 on trade flows that it is greater for countries with RTA. In addition, we also find a negative impact for a set of four indicators related to government responses against COVID-19, although a substantial variation in the impact on trade of the different measures is not observable. Furthermore, our results show that the COVID impacts on trade are only negative when income levels for exporter and importer country with regional trade agreements are identical, and in particular for high-income level countries.

These results pose important policy recommendations. The current trade shock induced by COVID-19 is still reshaping the world economy at the moment of writing these lines. However, current effects on trade can be considered as less detrimental than in the first wave from March to May 2020. The reason is contingent on countries’ capacity of adaptation to the different stages of the crisis. Countries may need to mitigate this trade shock by implementing public expenditure programs, as well as encouraging private investment. Such governmental actions may require further institutional initiatives, given the importance of the latter’s sizeable effects on trade flows (e.g., [ 47 ]). Nevertheless, countrywide attention has currently shifted towards vaccines, which may determine the future formulation of policies which concentrate vaccines on a small group of producers [ 77 ]. The transition to a non-COVID-19 context is expected to depend strongly on the vaccination efforts that are being undertaken by most countries. It is fundamental for countries to remain competitive throughout the course of the COVID-19 pandemic, simultaneously rebuilding wherever possible their trade relationships.

Finally, this manuscript presents certain limitations and avenues that must be taken into consideration for future research. First, the current study only offers a preliminary impact of COVID-19 on trade, as the shock is currently ongoing. The final magnitude of the shock may be assessed once it is over. Second, we only consider aggregate trade and the impact of COVID-19 on trade may depend on the sectoral comparative advantage of each country, as shown by the previous literature [ 23 ]. Hence, we may use trade data disaggregated by sectors, although we acknowledge that sectoral trade data availability is less forthcoming than its aggregate counterpart. Third, the existence of a subset of COVID-19 stringency indicators although highly correlated with the stringency index used in this article, may be capturing measures in very specific areas.

The analysis may also be extended to services trade flows in line with [ 25 ] approach. It would also be convenient to replicate these results for the subnational level. Despite recent efforts to estimate inter and intraregional trade flows in specific areas or territories, such as the European Union [ 78 ], this data is elaborated with a considerable time lag much larger than that for country data, and such analysis is not expected to be possible in the near future. Finally, it is necessary to acknowledge the importance of firms as international trade actors since there are substantial productivity differences across exporters. For this reason, it would be convenient to extend these findings to the firm level, as studied by [ 79 ] for Colombian firms.

Supporting information

S1 table. list of exporting countries..

High-income countries in bold.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s001

S2 Table. Main descriptive statistics.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s002

S3 Table. Results with one lag of COVID-19 government response indicators estimated by PPML, January 2019–October 2020.

Dependent variable is trade flows. Robust standard errors in parentheses, such as *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. All the specifications include exporter-month, importer-month and pair fixed effects.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s003

S4 Table. Robustness: Imports, M. Results by COVID-19 government response indicator estimated by PPML, January 2019–October 2020.

Robust standard errors in parentheses, such as *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. All the specifications include exporter-month, importer-month and pair fixed effects.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s004

S5 Table. One lag of COVID-19 government response indicator.

Results by income levels. Estimated by PPML, January 2019–October 2020. Dependent variable is exports. Robust standard errors in parentheses, such as *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Each COVID-19 indicator is estimated on a different regression but paired in the same column for the sake of brevity. All the specifications include exporter-month, importer-month and pair fixed effects.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s005

S6 Table. Robustness: Imports, M. Results by income levels and COVID-19 indicators estimated by PPML, January 2019-October 2020.

Dependent variable is imports. Robust standard errors in parentheses, such as *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Each COVID-19 indicator is estimated on a different regression but paired in the same column for the sake of brevity. All the specifications include exporter-month, importer-month and pair fixed effects.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0258356.s006

Acknowledgments

We thank two anonymous reviewers for their useful comments, which have contributed to improving the quality of the manuscript. Comments received from attendants of XXII Conference on International Economics and XXIII Applied Economics Meetings are also gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed are purely those of the authors and cannot under any circumstances be regarded as stating an official position on the part of the European Commission.

  • View Article
  • Google Scholar
  • 2. Baker SR, Terry SJ, Bloom N, Davis SJ. COVID-Induced Economic Uncertainty. (No. w26983). National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge. 2020. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26983 .
  • 10. De Lucio J, Minguez R, Minondo A, Requena F. The impact of COVID-19 containment measures on Trade. Department of Applied Economics II, Universidad de Valencia. WP 2101. 2020.
  • 16. Maliszewska M, Mattoo A, van der Mensbrugghe D. The Potential Impact of COVID-19 on GDP and Trade: A Preliminary Assessment. Washington, DC, USA: The World Bank wp 9211; 2020.
  • 19. Calderón C. Do free trade agreements enhance the transmission of shocks across countries?. Santiago de Chile: WP Banco Central de Chile 213; 2003.
  • 26. Hayakawa K, Kohei I. Who sends me face masks? Evidence for the impacts of COVID-19 on international trade in medical goods. Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO). 2021;810.
  • PubMed/NCBI
  • 29. WTO. Trade Cost Index: Evolution, Incidence and Determinants: Background Note. Geneva: World Trade Organization. 2021.
  • 34. Khorana S, Martínez-Zarzoso I, Ali S. The Impact of COVID-19 on the Global and Intra-Commonwealth Trade in Goods. International Trade Working Paper 2021/08.London: Commonwealth Secretariat. 2021.
  • 42. Cevik S. Going Viral: A Gravity Model of Infectious Diseases and Tourism Flows: International Monetary Fund; 2020.
  • 45. Tinbergen J. Shaping the World Economy; Suggestions for an International Economic Policy: Twentieth Century Fund, New York; 1962.
  • 46. Head K, Mayer T. Illusory border effects. In: van Bergeijk , Peter A. G., Brakman S, editors. The Gravity Model in International Trade: Advances and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2010. pp. 165–192.
  • 56. Beverelli C, Keck A, Larch M, Yotov YV. Institutions, Trade and Development: A Quantitative Analysis. CESifo Working Paper. 2018;6920.
  • 65. WTO. Trade statistics and Outlook. Trade shows signs of rebound from COVID-19, recovery still uncertain. Geneva: World Trade Organization. 2020.
  • 68. OECD. Elderly population. 2014. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1787/8d805ea1-en .
  • 71. Yotov YV, Piermartini R, Monteiro JA, Larch M. An advanced guide to trade policy analysis: The structural gravity model. Geneva: World Trade Organization. 2016.
  • 74. Hausmann R, Hidalgo CA, Bustos S. The Atlas of Economic Complexity: Mapping Paths to Prosperity. Cambridge, MA, USA: The MIT Press; 2014.
  • 77. Evenett SJ, Rocha N, Hoekman B, Ruta M. The Covid-19 Vaccine Production Club: Will Value Chains Temper Nationalism?. Washington, D.C: The World Bank; 2021.
  • 78. Thissen M, Ivanova O, Mandras G, Husby T. European NUTS 2 regions: construction of interregional trade-linked Supply and Use tables with consistent transport flows. European Commission. 2019.

research paper on import and export

Search form

Make a Gift

Department of Economics

  • Undergraduate

Operations Research Analyst at Export-Import Bank of the United States

Employer: Export-Import Bank of the United States

Expires: 09/25/2024

This Operations Research Analyst position is located in the Office of Policy Analysis & International Relations (OPAIR) and may be for either the Policy Analysis Division or International Relations Division within OPAIR. The Policy Analysis Division is responsible for EXIM's policy analysis, program design, and evaluation. The International Relations Division is responsible for EXIM's involvement in and relationships with the international organizations, associations, and regulatory bodies that affect official export credits (e.g. OECD, Berne Union, G7/12/20 and WTO). The employee works under the general direction of the Vice President of Policy Analysis, Vice President of International Relations, or his/her/their designee.

COMMENTS

  1. (PDF) A Study on Performance Evaluation of Imports and Exports on

    This paper explore the performance of imports and exports economic growth in India. Exports refer to the selling goods and services produced in the home country. Exports have played an gradually ...

  2. (PDF) IMPACT OF EXPORTS AND IMPORTS ON ECONOMIC GROWTH ...

    This paper investigates the relationship between exports, imports, and economic growth in Panama. In order to achieve this purpose, annual data for the periods between 1980 and 2015 was tested by ...

  3. (PDF) Import, Export and Economic Growth: the Case of ...

    DF test suggest for VECM. This paper has focused on exploring the relationship between import and GDP growth of Bangladesh fot the time period (1981-1992) of time series data [13].From the ...

  4. Rising Import Tariffs, Falling Export Growth: When Modern Supply Chains

    For the average affected firm, the implied cost is $900 per worker in new duties. We construct product-level measures of exporters' exposure to import tariff increases and estimate the impact on U.S. export growth. The most exposed products had relatively lower export growth in 2018-2019, with larger effects in 2019.

  5. Research on the Impact of COVID-19 on Import and Export Strategies

    Property 3. When a pandemic occurs in the exporting country, the exporting country's subsidies for its own enterprises will increase the export volume of its own enterprises, reduce the output of the importing enterprises, and lower the price of the product; the import quarantine fees imposed by the importing country on the exporting country will reduce the export of the exporting country ...

  6. How Terms of Trade Impact Economic Growth: The Case of the United

    The terms of trade can examine as the total ratio of export and import of a country during a specific period that can be written as TOT = P EX / P IM ... the paper offers a conclusion, study limitations, and suggestions for additional research and asks readers to think about the consequences of the policy recommendations based on study's ...

  7. PDF Analyzing the Relationship Between Trade and Economic Growth

    This paper examines how a country's amount of total trade spurs economic growth within countries. The paper will analyze how the total trade activity, measured as the combined level of exports and imports, impacts economic growth, measured as changes in GDP per capita. The model is expanded to include a

  8. Exporter-importer business relationships: Past empirical research and

    1. Introduction. Exporting and importing have been the traditional and most common methods of exchanging products and services across countries since time immemorial (Samiee, Leonidou, & Aykol, 2014).However, although the economists' explanations of international trade have been primarily based on the inter-dependencies between nations with regard to their factors of production, business ...

  9. Export- and import-based economic models for predicting global trade

    1. Introduction. Foreign trade is key to modern economic activities and a driving force for economic growth and globalization. Since the end of World War II, because of the decline in trade barriers, technological changes in telecommunications and transportation, and the development of the Internet, the speed of global trade activities has increased, and economies worldwide have been ...

  10. Import and export resilience of the global oil trade network

    In this paper, the aim is to analyze the global oil trade network structure and its resilience to shocks. First, the structure of the global oil trade network between 178 countries is determined. Second, the stability degree of all countries in oil export and import networks is calculated based on diversity principles.

  11. The Profile of Research on Exporter-Importer Relationships: A

    ABSTRACT. This article presents a chronological analysis of bibliographic and thematic aspects of exporter-importer business relationships research based on a systematic review of 211 articles published between the years 1975 and 2017 in business journals.

  12. Firms' exporting and importing activities: is there a two-way

    The literature on firm heterogeneity and trade has highlighted that most trading firms tend to engage in both importing and exporting activities. This paper provides some evidence that helps understanding to what extent this is the result of a two-way relationship. Using firm-level data for a group of 27 Eastern European and Central Asian countries from the World Bank Business Environment and ...

  13. Trade and growth in developing countries: the role of export

    We investigate the trade-economic growth nexus in developing countries considering the structure of the external sector. The economic literature has examined the effects on growth of export composition, export diversification and import composition, individually. We add to this discussion by jointly evaluating the role of these three factors in the trade-economic growth nexus. The assessment ...

  14. PDF Imports, Exports and Foreign Direct Investment Interactions and Their

    FDI inflows to Asia accounted for 17.41% and 17.18% of the world FDI inflows on average during 1994-1999 and 2000-2005. This seems to suggest a positive link between international trade and investment in the region. Table 1 also shows the increasing rate of exports, import, and FDI inflows in different part of the world.

  15. Full article: Effects of export and technology on economic growth

    Table 6. provides empirical evidence of the positive and significant effect of export and technology on economic growth in the long-run. If the export increases by 1%, economic growth (lnY) will follow by 0.18% increase; similarly, if the technology increases by 1%, economic growth will also increase by 0.06%.

  16. PDF Impact of exports and imports on the economic growth

    Title: Impact of exports and imports on the economic growth Authors: Bashir Al Hemzawi and Natacha Umutoni Tutor: Dorothea Schäfer Date: nd2021-May-22 Key terms: imports, exports, economic growth, international trade, Rwanda Abstract Background: In today's world, any country cannot live in economic isolation. All aspects of a

  17. Full article: Impact of regional trade agreements on export efficiency

    Over the period (2008-2018), service exports recorded a growth of 94% ($139 to$205 billion) vis-à-vis 66% ($200-$332billion) in goods. Over 2011-2018, goods export has stagnated with ~7% overall growth compared to ~55% in services (Figure 2).The stagnating exports (as a % of GDP) during 2014-16 was mainly attributed to the challenging global economic situation and plunge in the crude ...

  18. (Pdf) a Study on Growth and Impacts of India'S Foreign Trade

    This study main investigates that the growth of Exports, Imports and Trade Balance from 1949-50 to 2018-19 in India. It also reveals that the India's export profile state wise share for 2016-17 ...

  19. Investigating Export Determinants: A Time Series Evidence From Canada

    The main idea of this research is to explore important factors that may impact export performance for a developed economy like Canada. In this context, the present study takes into account the role of the real effective exchange rate, the real interest rate, government final consumption expenditures, energy consumption per capita and total population for testing the export performance.

  20. Exploring Import-led Growth in India: Evidence from the Post-reform

    The present article studies whether the ELG, ILG, growth-led export (GLE) and growth-led import (GLI) propositions hold in India for the post-reform period. Accordingly, the short-run and the long-run impacts of exports, imports, exchange rate and trade openness on income are assessed. The analysis finds prominent evidence of ILG hypothesis ...

  21. PDF The Dynamics of Relationship between Exports, Import and ...

    Research in Humanities & Soc. Sciences [I.F. = 0.352] , Issue: 7, July: 2015 ... (2015) in their paper "Exports, Imports and Economic Growth in India: An Empirical Analysis" testing the Export Led Growth Hypothesis for India with annual time series data from 1980 to 2013.they found that within the period of 1980 to 2013, the variables are ...

  22. Trade Policy Implications of a Changing World: Tariffs and Import

    IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit ... as it is able to import more for the same amount of exports. In other words, its tariff action has a negative externality on its trading partners' terms-of-trade. However, if all countries acted on this impulse, terms-of-trade gains would cancel ...

  23. Effects of COVID-19 on trade flows: Measuring their impact ...

    This paper examines the impact of COVID-19 on bilateral trade flows using a state-of-the-art gravity model of trade. Using the monthly trade data of 68 countries exporting across 222 destinations between January 2019 and October 2020, our results are threefold. First, we find a greater negative impact of COVID-19 on bilateral trade for those countries that were members of regional trade ...

  24. Operations Research Analyst at Export-Import Bank of the United States

    Employer: Export-Import Bank of the United States . Expires: 09/25/2024 . This Operations Research Analyst position is located in the Office of Policy Analysis & International Relations (OPAIR) and may be for either the Policy Analysis Division or International Relations Division within OPAIR. The Policy Analysis Division is responsible for ...

  25. Research Note

    However, the claim, reinforced in government documents, is based on an assumption that any spending by international students while studying in Australia is an 'export'. This means that the expenditure of a student who is working while studying, and spends the money they earn locally in the Australian economy, is classified as export revenue.